† Corresponding author. E-mail:
Quantum entanglement has emerged as a new resource to enhance cooperation and remove dilemmas. This paper aims to explore conditions under which full cooperation is achievable even when the information of payoff is incomplete. Based on the quantum version of the extended classical cash in a hat game, we demonstrate that quantum entanglement may be used for achieving full cooperation or avoiding moral hazards with the reasonable profit distribution policies even when the profit is uncertain to a certain degree. This research further suggests that the fairness of profit distribution should play an important role in promoting full cooperation. It is hopeful that quantum entanglement and fairness will promote full cooperation among distant people from various interest groups when quantum networks and quantum entanglement are accessible to the public.
With the development of quantum technology, we would like to ask the following questions: What will quantum information technology bring to daily life in the future? What will happen when quantum networks and quantum entanglements are not only available for scientists, but also accessible to the general public? In this paper, we aim to investigate the conditions on which the quantization of classical games can bring full cooperation even when the information of payoff is incomplete.
Classical game theory concerns the study of multi-person decision problems and plays an important role in economics, social sciences, communication, and biology. The work of Neumann and Morgenstern[1] laid the foundation of classical game theory, but a better comprehension was achieved mainly due to the contribution of John Nash.[2] In 1999, Meyer[3] proposed the first quantized game. It has been demonstrated that a quantum game can offer new ways to enhance cooperation, to remove dilemma, and to change equilibrium.[4,5] Eisert et al.[6] first introduced the quantum prisoners’ dilemma game, in which the players succeeded in escaping the dilemma. Researchers also studied quantum auctions,[7] the quantum battle of sexes,[8,9] quantum gambling,[10] quantum duel,[11,12] quantum Russian roulette,[13,14] quantum Hawk–Dove game,[15] quantum Parrondo game,[16] quantum magic squares game,[17,18] etc.
Marinatto and Weber[19] took inspiration from Ref. [6] and introduced another interesting and acceptable scheme for the analysis of nonzero sum games by means of quantum strategies. Since then many researchers followed the scheme to analyze many specific games in the quantum domain, and Nawaz and Toor[20] generalized the MW quantization scheme[19] for two-person nonzero sum games.
Besides the aforementioned researches, Pappa and his coauthors[21] presented the first conflicting interest Bayesian game in which quantum mechanics leads to a higher total payoff. More conflicting interest games were further discussed by Situ[22] and other researchers.
This paper will focus on games of players with different but common interests, and we aim to explore the conditions under which full cooperation is achievable even when the information of payoff is incomplete. Recently, our research group[23] has explored the quantum “cash in a hat” game, whose classical version is a famous simplified model between a borrower and a lender in economics. It has been demonstrated in Ref. [23] that entanglement resources can be helpful in avoiding moral hazards. Working on the extended cash in a hat game with different profit distribution policies, we show that the fairness of profit distribution policies plays an important role in promoting the cooperation or avoiding moral hazards.
First, let us consider the extended classical cash in a hat game with different distribution policies under different investments. There are two players, Alice and Bob, each with two choices. Alice can put a small (KS) or a large amount of coins (KL) into a hat according to her wishes. Then she gives the hat with her investment to Bob. Bob can add the same amount of coins or simply take all the cash away. The payoff of this game is shown in Table
The classical cash in a hat game is a sequential game, and we plot a decision tree in Fig.
Now, let us briefly analyze the aforementioned extended cash in a hat game. When Alice puts small investment KS into the hat (strategy D), Bob will match the cash (strategy C) in order to maximize his own profit if
However, if Bob does not know the previous moves of Alice, the extended classical cash in a hat game can be considered as a simultaneous game. Therefore, we represent the extended classical cash in a hat game in the so-called normal form as shown in Table
Here, the moral hazard of this classical game is the risk that the borrower may evade his repayment. We have no way to avoid the problem of moral hazard in the classical cash in a hat game. The equilibrium can be obtained through the method called backward induction. Moral hazard forces the investor to reduce her investment because Alice may wonder whether or not Bob will take the cash away if she chooses strategy C, that is to say, the investor prefers strategy D. Thus, we can easily find that the equilibrium solution of this game ends up in DC. However, we prefer that the game ends up in CC obviously, since CC is not only Pareto optimal, but also maximizes the welfare of the society.
It should be underlined that we can avoid moral hazard if
Based on the aforementioned discussion, we recognize that the moral hazard issue should be explored only when the following payoff conditions are satisfied:
However, the information of TL may be incomplete and we only know
Subsequently, we will further explore the sufficient conditions under which the moral hazard can be solved and players can reach the Pareto optimal solution. For simplicity, we borrow the idea from Refs. [6] and [27] and plot the physical model of the quantum-like cash in a hat game in Fig.
The state for the quantum-like version of the extended cash in a hat game is described by a vector in a Hilbert space spanned by the basics
Unitary operations
We respectively associate Aliceʼs and Bobʼs classical strategies with operations
The strategic moves of Alice and Bob are associated with unitary operations
It can be proved that this quantum-like game is reduced to the classical game when γ = 0. In case DD, the final state is given by
Here, only a single new quantized strategy (strategy Q) is introduced in our quantum-like version of the extended cash in a hat game. For Alice,
Tables
For the aforementioned quantum-like game, a novel Nash equilibrium QQ arises with payoffs (
For example, let KS = 1, KL = 3, TS = 3, and
We can conclude from Table
One can also choose βS = 2/3 and βL = 1/2. The moral hazard in the extended classical cash in a hat game is overcome if the following entanglement condition is satisfied:
The aforementioned analysis and examples suggest that even the information of payoff is incomplete, the quantum physical resources including quantum entanglement provide us with an alternative scheme to enhance the cooperation and overcome the constraints of social morals if the players are assumed to be ideally rational and the payoff conditions given by Eqs. (
In summary, quantum entanglement, with equitable profit distribution policies, can be used for promoting full cooperation or avoiding moral hazards even when the information of payoff is incomplete, but quantum entanglement cannot work without reasonable or fair profit distributions policies. In other words, entanglement cannot enhance the cooperation if the profit distribution polices are not reasonable or fair. Our recent research[28] also indicates that entanglement can also be utilized to enhance the cooperation of distant players with the help of quantum networks. We come to realize that neither quantum entanglement nor quantum network can offer full cooperation without fair profit distribution policies. Full cooperation relies on not only the degree of quantum entanglement but also the degree of fairness. We will further explore full cooperation problems for hybrid noncooperative–cooperative games[29,30] and repeated games with incomplete information.[31] In our opinion, it is a worthy research topic to understand the conditions under which full cooperation is achievable among distant people from different interest groups.
[1] | |
[2] | |
[3] | |
[4] | |
[5] | |
[6] | |
[7] | |
[8] | |
[9] | |
[10] | |
[11] | |
[12] | |
[13] | |
[14] | |
[15] | |
[16] | |
[17] | |
[18] | |
[19] | |
[20] | |
[21] | |
[22] | |
[23] | |
[24] | |
[25] | |
[26] | |
[27] | |
[28] | |
[29] | |
[30] | |
[31] |